Portubots and Englifleshes: Why comparative advantage doesn't guarantee there will always be jobs for humans
[Speaking of jobs, if anyone knows of any work going from Sydney or remotely- let me know. Also, if you’ve been thinking about subscribing as thanks for my content, I’d be very grateful. Seeking work post PhD is an ordeal!]
“However, even though jobs where humans have absolute advantage may be narrowing, there is little reason to expect an end to human work. The reason stems from a classic idea in economics: comparative advantage.
Even in a world where robots have absolute advantage in everything — meaning robots can do everything more efficiently than humans can — robots will be deployed where they have the greatest relative productivity advantage. Humans, meanwhile, will work where they have the smallest disadvantage. If robots can produce 10 times as many automobiles per day as a team of humans, but only twice as many houses, it makes sense to have the robots specialize and focus full-time where they’re relatively most efficient, in order to maximize output. Therefore, even though people are a bit worse than robots at building houses, that job still falls to humans.”
- Lori G. Kletzer, Harvard Business Review
There’s a story one hears from time to time, among those perhaps a little inordinately proud that they completed Econ 101, that purports to explain why even if robots are better at human at everything, nonetheless, there will still be jobs for humans. This inventive story is based on abusing the theory of comparative advantage in economics and burdening this reliable workhorse of an idea with more weight than it can bear. Lori Kletzer, an actual economist, who I quote above eloquently expresses the basics of the idea. For those readers not yet familiar with the theory of comparative advantage I’ve included a summary below, courtesy of Wikipedia.
Summary of comparative advantage courtesy of Wikipedia the free encyclopedia
“In a famous example, Ricardo considers a world economy consisting of two countries, Portugal and England, each producing two goods of identical quality. In Portugal, the a priori more efficient country, it is possible to produce wine and cloth with less labor than it would take to produce the same quantities in England. However, the relative costs or ranking of the cost of producing those two goods differ between the countries.
Hours of work necessary to produce one unit:
In this illustration, England could commit 100 hours of labor to produce one unit of cloth or produce 5/6 units of wine. Meanwhile, in comparison, Portugal could commit 100 hours of labor to produce 10/9 units of cloth or produce 10/8 units of wine. Portugal possesses an absolute advantage in producing both cloth and wine due to more produced per hour (since 10/9 > 1). If the capital and labor were mobile, both wine and cloth should be made in Portugal, with the capital and labor of England removed there.[12] If they were not mobile, as Ricardo believed them to be generally, then England's comparative advantage (due to lower opportunity cost) in producing cloth means that it has an incentive to produce more of that good which is relatively cheaper for them to produce than the other—assuming they have an advantageous opportunity to trade in the marketplace for the other more difficult to produce good.
In essence, the theory of comparative advantage in relation to international trade shows that even if country X is better at producing both commodities A & B than country Y, nevertheless”
Now, let’s have Claude 3 take on the persona of a smarmy economics explainer to show how some try to extend this to humans and machines
I thought, in an article on human labor being replaced with machine labor, it would be an excellent experiment to explore whether the position of glib economics explainer could be replaced by robots. The initial results are promising! Here’s Claude 3 Opus tasked with making an economics-explainer-style argument that comparative advantage proves AI will never put humans out of a job:
Adjusts tie and clears throat Ah yes, the question of superhuman AI and its potential impact on human employment. It's a topic that's been on my mind lately, even more so than the fascinating market dynamics at play in the local craft beer scene. chuckles
You see, the key to understanding why humans won't necessarily lose out in the face of superhuman AI lies in the economic principle of comparative advantage. This principle, first introduced by David Ricardo in the early 19th century, states that even if one entity (in this case, AI) is more efficient at producing all goods or services, there can still be mutual benefits from specialization and trade.
Let's consider a simplified example. Imagine a world where superhuman AI can perform both task A and task B more efficiently than humans. However, the AI's relative advantage in task A is greater than its relative advantage in task B. In this scenario, the AI would specialize in task A, while humans would specialize in task B. This specialization leads to increased overall productivity and economic output.
Now, you might be thinking, "But what if the AI becomes so advanced that it has an absolute advantage in both tasks?" Well, that's where the beauty of comparative advantage shines through. Even in this case, as long as the opportunity cost of the AI performing task B is higher than the opportunity cost of humans performing task B, there will still be an incentive for the AI to specialize in task A and for humans to specialize in task B.
Furthermore, as AI takes over certain tasks, it frees up human labor to focus on new and creative endeavors. Throughout history, we've seen technological advancements displace workers in specific industries, but also create entirely new job categories. The introduction of automobiles, for example, led to a decline in horse-related jobs but sparked a boom in the automotive industry and related fields.
leans in, eyes sparkling with excitement The interaction between superhuman AI and human labor is akin to the dynamic interplay between different countries in international trade. Each entity, whether human or AI, will gravitate towards the tasks in which it has a comparative advantage. This process drives innovation, efficiency, and ultimately, economic growth.
Of course, this transition won't be without its challenges. Education and retraining programs will be crucial in helping workers adapt to the changing economic landscape. But with the right policies in place, the rise of superhuman AI could lead to a new era of prosperity and opportunity for humans.
sits back, smiling So, the next time you find yourself pondering the future of work while sipping on a locally-sourced IPA, remember the power of comparative advantage. It's not just a theory; it's a guiding principle that has stood the test of time and will continue to shape our economic destiny in the age of AI. raises glass Cheers to that!
Why this doesn’t work
Let us imagine that the story of Portugal and England is a little bit different.
First of all, the Portuguese and English can move around as they like, and retain their relative skills wherever they are. Second of all, all the land that can be used to make cloth or wine belongs to capitalists, who will assign that land based on economic expediency. Third, and crucially, Portuguese people have this magic ritual they can perform to quickly create new adult Portuguese, and this ritual doesn’t cost very much.
These assumptions are meant to mirror how things are between humans and robots in a hypothetical world of cheap AGI and robots. Robots can make more robots and there isn’t any capital that is exclusively accessible by humans, except perhaps a few pockets that belong to small producers and sole traders.
To simplify somewhat, suppose:
1. Robots are vastly better than humans at everything,
2. Robots are cheap to make
3. There is no capital that is exclusively reserved for humans, but capital will be assigned by the capitalist to whoever, robot or human, can use it most efficiently.
4. And the stock of capital creates a limited number of ‘spaces’ for workers, human or robot (i.e., you can’t have infinite workers off a finite capital stock)
Then the comparative advantage will not, as far as I can tell, ensure employment for humans.
I’ll admit, that working through the maths of the general case is a bit beyond me, but consider the case of a single employer, with two production techniques:
1 Pickaxe plus 1 robot= 1000 dollars in income per period
1 Pickaxe plus 1 human= 100 dollars in income per period
Now suppose pickaxes cost 20 dollars to make, and robots cost 50 dollars to make. Human wages are, for the sake of argument, so low as to be effectively zero. The employer is going to be better off assigning pickaxes to robots. Any assignment of humans to pickaxes will only happen if the employer starts out with more pickaxes than robots, and will only be temporary until the employer can afford to get robots to replace the humans and have the pickaxes be operated by the vastly more efficient robots.
Could other complexities ensure that it is still worth hiring humans for some reason or other? Sure, but the Ricardian story of comparative advantage alone won’t get us there, because the fundamental assumptions of the Portugal versus England case are breached.
Beware of people who try to prove too much with too little. Human labor is ultimately just another category of input into production processes, albeit a very versatile one. There can be no a priori guarantee that it will always find an economic use.
Alas that this point needs to be made, and to economists sometimes no less. But thank you for making it.
I'll note work is a means to an end, not an end in itself. The end of work is not problematic, poverty is. Hugely scaling wealth does not seem like a problem...